Do Most Countries Elect Their Government Leader by Majority Rule?

 

Prime Minister Scheer?

 

Co-blogger Scott Sumner, over at his own blog, themoneyillusion, writes:

Other countries generally elect their president by majority vote (although a few “ceremonial” presidents are picked by an EC, as in India).

He might be correct if he literally means “president.” But Scott seems to be comparing the United States electoral college to how the rest of the democratic world elects its governments’ main leaders, whether they’re called President, Prime Minister, or something else.

The other governments I know best–Canada, where I grew up, eh?, the United Kingdom, Australia, and New Zealand–don’t elect their Prime Minister by majority vote. They have a Parliamentary system and the party with the most seats gets to form the government. In a way, that’s like the Electoral College.

Indeed, although in Canada’s 2019 national election no party won a majority of the vote, the party that won the plurality was the Conservative Party. Scheer’s Conservative Party won 34.34 percent of the vote and Prime Minister Justin Trudeau’s Liberal Party won 33.12 percent. If it had been the party with the most votes that determines the Prime Minister, we would be referring to Prime Minister Andrew Scheer.

 

(0 COMMENTS)

Read More

A Key Characteristic of a Banana Republic

Over at The Money Illusion, fellow EconLog blogger Scott Sumner lays out 21 characteristics of a banana republic. He points out that it’s not a complete list. I agree.

In particular, there’s one characteristic missing, a characteristic that has been quite relevant in the United States and in major parts of the world since early April.

It is this:

Does the government prevent people from practicing their occupation and shut down huge parts of the economy based on the idea, not that people are sick and might spread their sickness to others, but that people might be sick, even though most of them aren’t, and might spread their sickness to others? And relatedly, does it threaten people who could easily prove themselves not to be sick with fines and/or jail sentences for not complying?

Also, related, does the government keep changing its rationale for the shutdowns.

 

(0 COMMENTS)

Read More

Five Books on Macroeconomics

Recently, Raffaele Rossi offered his recommendations for the best macroeconomics textbooks at Five Books. Here, Arnold Kling offers his recommendations:

 

 

Macroeconomic Patterns and Stories, by Edward Leamer.  This provides an excellent introduction to the data that are central to macroeconomics—how they are collected and what they mean.  Although it is framed as an introductory textbook for business school students, it is valuable for economists at all levels.  Leamer wisely steers the reader away from thinking in terms of systems of equations and instead looks for patterns in the data and stories that could explain those patterns.   Note that I recently suggested that Leamer deserves a Nobel Prize for his insights into empirical methods in economics.

 

Manias, Panics, and Crashes, by Charles P. Kindleberger and Robert Z. Aliber.  The late Charles Kindleberger was an economic historian, and I believe a historian’s perspective is crucial for looking at macroeconomics.  After all, there are no repeatable experiments in macroeconomics, only historical episodes.  Kindleberger looks at the most dramatic episodes in history, using the framework of financial instability developed by Hyman Minsky.  Kindleberger is a better expositor than Minsky.  Also,  Kindleberger emphasizes the phenomenon of “displacement,” in which a sudden change in world conditions, brought about by a major new discovery or the outcome of a war, triggers a dangerous mania.  My own thinking about macroeconomics is a combination of Kindleberger-Minsky and Fischer Black (below).

 

The Midas Paradox, by Scott Sumner.  Sumner tells the story of the Great Depression, probably the most important episode in macroeconomic history.  Sumner believes in a monetarist interpretation of the Depression.  Although I personally do not subscribe to this framework, his book provides an outstanding exposition of this important macroeconomic theory.

 

Exploring General Equilibrium, by Fischer Black.  If Kindleberger-Minsky macroeconomics is heterodox, Black’s macro was even more so.  Black does away with conventional aggregate demand and aggregate supply altogether, and instead constructs a theory of economic fluctuations based on general equilibrium, with physical and human capital sometimes suffering from rapid obsolescence.  Black even denies the relationship between money and inflation!  Tyler Cowen wrote, “It’s not an easy book for most people to read, as Black just comes out and states what he thinks, without much in the way of trappings or preliminaries or traditional narrative structure. There are also no models, just strings of statements about models.That said, virtually every sentence has substance.It is one of my favorite books in economics and it still contains many unmined insights.“

 

Macroeconomics, by J. Bradford Delong and Martha L. Olney.  I see this as a textbook that presents what I call the “academic” approach to macro, treating the economy as a system of equations.  This is not an approach that I share, but it is certainly important in the history of economic thought.  When I read the first edition of this book, I was impressed by its coverage of the topics of economic growth and international macro.  A more recent textbook that also emphasizes economic growth is Modern Principles of Macroeconomics, by Tyler Cowen and Alex Tabarrok.

Arnold Kling is the author of Specialization and Trade, which includes chapters that spell out his views of macroeconomics.

 

 


As an Amazon Associate Econlib may earn from qualifying purchases.

(0 COMMENTS)

Read More